The Link Among Trade, Fdi and Immigration
Abstract
Using the gravity model, this paper provides a new empirical framework that analyzes the importance of the link among trade, FDI, and immigration. A further significant contribution of this analysis is the appropriate handling of a large num- ber of zeroes in migration statistics. In this way, the unbalanced panel database of the 15 core European member states (EU15) as destination countries is formed. The results of the estimation show that the introduced explanatory variables, such as the common language, destination country’s population, and great circle distance between two countries, represent the most significant deterministic factors that ge- nerally explain the share of the immigrant population. It is also confirmed that the sending country’s population, trade, FDI, and sending country’s landlocked position are important determinants positively influencing the share of immigration.
Downloads
References
Anderson, J. E. (1979). Theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American Economic Review, 69,106–116.
Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93, 170–192. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/000282803321455214
Afman, E. R., & Maurel, M. (2010). Diplomatic relation and trade reorientation in transition countries. In P.
A. G. van Bergeijk & S. Brakman (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade (pp. 278–295). New York: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511762109.010
Baldwin, R., & Harrigan, J. (2007). Zeroes, quality and spaces: Trade theory and trade evidence. NBER Working Paper (No. 13214), Cambridge, MA.
Bergeijk, A. G. P., & Brakman, S. (2010). The gravity model in international trade. New York: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511762109
Bergstrand, J. H. (1985). The gravity equation in inter- national trade: Some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67, 474–481. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1925976
Bergstrand, J. H. (1989). The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and empirical evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 143–153. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1928061
Bosker, E. M., & Garretsen, H. (2010). Trade costs, markets access, and economic geography. In P. A. G. van Bergeijk & S. Brakman (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade(pp. 193–224). New York: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511762109.007
Brakman, S. G. G., Garretsen, H., & van Marrewijk, C. (2010). Economic and financial integration and the rise of cross-border M&As. In P. A. G. van Bergeijk & S. Brakman (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade (pp. 296–323). New York: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511762109.011
Dunlevy, A. J. (2006). The influence of corruption and language on the protrade effect of immigrants: Evidence from the American states. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(1), 182–186. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/rest.2006.88.1.182
Foad, H. (2011). FDI and immigration: A regional analysis. The Annals of Regional Science. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00168-011-0438-4
Frankel, A. J., & Romer, D. (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, 89(3), 379–399. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.379
Gaston, N., & Douglas, N. R. (2011). Bridging trade theory and labour econometrics: The effects of internatio- nal migration. Journal of Economic Surveys. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00696.x
Girma, S., & Zhihao, Y. (2002). The link between immigration and trade: Evidence from the United Kingdom. Review of World Economics, 138(1), 111–130.
Gould, D. M. (1994). Immigrant links to the home country: Empirical implications for U. S. bilateral trade flows. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76(2), 302–316. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2109884
Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Rubenstein, Y. (2008). Estimating trade flows: Trading partners and trading volumes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123, 441–487. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.2.441
Hijzen, A., & Wright, P. W. (2009). Migration, trade and wages. Journal of Population Economics, 23(4), 1189–1211. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00148-009-0241-z
Jansen, M. (2009). Temporary migration and bilateral trade flows. World Economy, 32(5), 735–753. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01167.x
Javorcik, S. B., Ozden, C., Spaternau, M., & Neagu, C. (2011). Migrant networks and foreign direct investments. Journal of Development Economics, 94(2), 231–241. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.01.012
Linnemann, H. (1966). An economic analysis of international trade flows. Amsterdam: Nord Holland.
Markusen, J. R. (1983). Factor movements and commodity trade as complements. Journal of International Economics, 14, 341–356. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(83)90009-0
Mundell, R. A. (1957). International trade and factor mobility. American Economic Review, 47(3), 321–335.
Murat, M. (2009). Migrant networks: Empirical im- plications for the Italian bilateral trade. International Economic Journal, 23(3), 371–390. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10168730903119435
Ortega, F., & Peri, G. (2011). The aggregate effects of trade and migration: Evidence from OECD countries. Queens College and CUNY and IZA Discussion Paper (No. 5604).
Peri, G. (2010). The trade creation effect of immigrants: Evidence from the remarkable case of Spain. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne déconomique, 43(4), 1433–1459. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540- 5982.2010.01620.x
Poot, J. (2010). International trade agreements and international migration. World Economy, 33(12), 1923–1954. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2010.01299.x
Rybczynski, T. M. (1955). Factor endowments and relative commodity prices. Economica, 22, 336–341. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2551188
Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. M. (2010). International environment arrangements and international trade. In
P. A. G. van Bergeijk & S. Brakman (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade (pp. 255–278). New York: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/ CBO9780511762109.009
Stein, E., & Duade, C. (2007). Longitude matters: Time zones and the location of foreign direct investment. Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 96–112. http:// dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.01.003
Santos, S. J., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/rest.88.4.641
Tai, H. T. S. (2009). Market structure and the link between migration and trade. Review of World Economics, 154(2), 225–245. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10290-009-0012-7
Tinbergen, J. (1962). Shaping the world economy: Suggestions for an international economic policy. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.
Warin, T., & Blakely, A. (2009). Choice or mimetism in the decision to migrate: A European illustration. Scientific Series, 38(2009).
White, R. (2007). Immigrant–trade links, transplanted home bias and network effects. Applied Economics, 39(7), 839–852. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840500447849
Zimmermann, K. F. (1994). European migration: Push and pull. In Proceedings Volume of World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, Supplement to the World Economic Review and the World Research Observer.